The Shape of Global Parasitism

A couple of days ago Buttonwood over at The Economist touched on my favourite topics: the growth of the Western service industry, the death of Western manufacturing, and the deep interconnectedness of the global economic system. His hook was that most claims of parasitism are at best not-straightforward, and at worst are unfounded. From The Economist:

Are all manufactured goods intrinsically superior to services? Would you rather have a wig or a haircut? Just as there is only so much food we can healthily consume, there is only so much physical stuff we need. We have service-dominated economies because people like to consume services from TV programmes through video games to leisure activities like eating out. When General Motors sells a car, the chances are that it is selling it to someone who works in the services sector; so who is the parasite in this situation?

At the national level, we can say that most countries cannot produce all the things they need (or at least desire). Britain, for example, needs food from abroad. So it needs industries that can export stuff in order to generate the earnings that pay for imports. Here the bankers start to look a lot more valuable; Britain’s invisible earnings from financial services are highly valuable.

A more realistic question might be “would I rather have a factory making hair clippers, or a cabal of lawyers, financiers and bureaucrats who readily declare themselves too-big-to-fail and hose themselves down in taxpayers’ liquidity?”

But nonetheless it is a relevant point — because it leads us onto the real question of why economies need to become more decentralised, and less reliant on externalities. To answer that we need to look at the shape of globalisation. People all around the globe have needs and wants, as well as labour, produce and capital to get those things they need and want. With globalisation, if someone has the technology, capital and know-how to start a factory manufacturing — for the sake of example — hair clippers, then they can start it wherever they believe it would be most profitable. The bounties of oil infrastructure, and the low cost of global shipping mean that that could be anywhere on the planet with access to resources, cheap labour, and free trade. And that has meant that cheap Chinese and Asian labour has allowed these nations to accumulate a vast productive base. This means that advanced economies like Britain and America — rich nations, with vast amounts of accumulated capital, technology, and know-how — can import the goods they once manufactured and turn their productive infrastructure to a service-led model — concentrating on industries like finance, telecommunications, information technology, and the creative arts. The beauty of globalisation is that they have given the West a free lunch, and allowed for an ever-greater stream of innovation in computing, artificial intelligence, robotics, and life sciences, as well as a dominant position in the global creative industries

But not everything that is beautiful is sustainable. The West moving requires oil, goods, and agriculture, and Western nations are increasingly importing more and more of these. And just so long as the global infrastructural systems holds together, this is all very well. But what happens if it doesn’t? We know that periods of free trade, free movement, and globalisation tend to be short-lived. Large complex systems — like the global economy — with trillions of inputs and outputs are highly fragile. From Nassim Taleb:

People talk about black swans but they don’t talk about robustness, which is the real lesson of the black swans.

It’s like saying a bridge is fragile. I can’t predict which truck is going to break it, so I have to look at it more in a structural form — what physicists call the percolation approach. You study the terrain. You don’t study the components. You see in finance, we study the random walk. Physicists study it percolation. They study the terrain — not a drunk person walking around — but the evolution of the terrain itself. Everything is dynamic. That is percolation.

And then you learn not to try to predict which truck is going to break that bridge. But you just look at bridges and say, “Oh, this bridge doesn’t have a great foundation. This other one does. And this one needs to be reinforced.” We can do a lot with the notion of robustness.

The global economy is like a bridge — lots and lots of trucks (events) drive over it, and we cannot predict which will break it — but we do know that for a variety of reasons — high Western indebtedness, the growth of Eastern military might, vulnerable oil reserves concentrated in hot-spots, vulnerable oil and shipping infrastructure, under-confidence and Keynesian liquidity traps, unexpected global conflict, climate change, solar flares, a global pandemic — that the global infrastructure is vulnerable to collapse. We don’t know when, or how it will happen, but we know that there is a lot of stress and strain on the bridge.

So countries, regions, institutions, individuals and groups that want to survive and thrive through any breakdown of global infrastructure and resultant turmoil need to be relatively self-sufficient in a number of domains: food production & consumption, energy generation and storage, labour, capital and so forth. Buttonwood’s article, meanwhile, delves into the debate on just how much debt the government can sustain, and whether or not we need to pay down our deficits quickly. This is really the same problem — debt creates fragility, because it leaves debtors with less margin for fiscal error. Finally, he concludes that in reality we are all subject to some kind of dependency:

Some humility is needed from both sides in the economic debate. We cannot run huge public sector deficits forever but that is not the same as saying that we should never run a deficit, nor that we should balance it now. We do not want “too much” government interference in the economy but there are plenty of vital services that the government provides. We are all of us economic parasites in a way, since we are dependent on the decisions and the well-being of others.

And there is the point — as humans we are all dependent on the sun’s heat and light. We’re dependent on the carbon, nitrogen, oxygen, hydrogen and phosphorus cycles. We’re dependent on the strength of our skeleton, the strength of our muscles and our brain function. We’re dependent on the social fabric of our families and communities. Why then are we allowing a system of globalisation persist that creates additional global fragility when we could so easily lessen the fragility and decentralise?

So the problem is not really parasitism, or over-reliance on services, or the export of jobs to the East, or the ridiculous and bulging levels of debt. The problem is the global fragility — hard to measure, define and quantify, but nonetheless very real — that this system of globalisation, and the above problems creates. We ignore fragility at out peril.

25 thoughts on “The Shape of Global Parasitism

  1. This is not just an international problem. All agricultural-based societies by definition are characterised by specialisation, rendering each of us dependent on others as we no longer individually have the broad skills to be self-sufficient. Countries are no different, only writ-large compared to the individual.

    The problem is that we divert resources away from base needs such as food and security to higher wants, leaving us vulnerable to systemic shocks. All interdependent systems are fragile by nature, but the alternative is a low-risk, low wealth society. Tilting the playing field in favour of low-paid manufacturing does precisely that in the long run. People decry services because they are less tangible, however this ambiguity resists the commodification of service products, thus retaining margins and profitability and delaying the onset of maturation within the product lifecycle. That is why our institutions are so important and should not ever be taken for granted. It takes a lot longer to create than to destroy, and to fail to protect that which makes us free and safe is to ultimately lose that which we take for granted. Better to make potential enemies mutually dependent to pursue the high-wealth, high-risk approach of maximising growth through productivity.

    • I’m talking about something very concrete: put solar panels on every roof in the West and we’re suddenly far less reliant on Arab oil. Tax Western manufacturing at zero, police the world less (raises insurance costs for Eastern goods), and invest in more supply chain infrastructure (3-D printing would be ideal) and suddenly that 9.1% unemployment becomes 4% as Western manufacturing becomes far more viable. Invest in urban farming (and vertical farming) and Western cities become far less vulnerable to an oil shock.

      None of these ideas cuts away from a predominantly service/knowledge-based economy. It’s just a re-engineering of the underlying infrastructure to make it less fragile to shocks and black swans.

  2. I agree wholeheartedly, but here in Australia they’re bringing in a carbon tax which will act like a reverse tarriff and kill off what little is left of manufacturing in this country. Instead they should invest in education and development in leading edge technology to get ahead of the curve rather than than competing in commoditized, large economies of scale manufactured products.

    • At least you Australians have great natural resources, plenty of additional agricultural potential, and a young, hard working population. But the carbon tax is a very, very bad idea. Manufacturers pay a lot, Macquarie pay nothing.

  3. Pingback: Stagnation Nation? « azizonomics

  4. Not read the article in “The Economist” so I may not be fully up-to-date on this issue.

    My thoughts:

    Indeed, services are just as good as hard/palpable products. But the crux of the problem is debt and deficits.

    If those services are just as valuable as the imported hard/palpable products, then why are those many DM countries running such large deficits and huge debts? You might say that some things like democracy and stability (that might for example give more value to UK banks) might not be fully priced in. But then the question arises: why wouldn’t the “approximately” efficient markets price in the true value of those services?

  5. Pingback: How to Crash the Price of Gold « azizonomics

  6. Keep up this good work, you have a nice blog over here with much good information! When you post some new stuff, I’ll visit your blog again and I’ll follow it.

  7. Pingback: European Leaders Scrabble For Agreement « azizonomics

  8. Pingback: The Only Chinese Hard Landing Will Be On America’s Head « azizonomics

  9. Pingback: The Start of the Sino-American Trade War « azizonomics

  10. Pingback: Mitt Romney & American Imperial Decline « azizonomics

  11. Pingback: The Dangers of the Era « azizonomics

  12. Pingback: Can I Have a Bailout? « azizonomics

  13. Pingback: Romney or Paul? « azizonomics

  14. Pingback: The Changing World « azizonomics

  15. hrough the ages man has been in cultivation. The Early man lived on cultivating the land around him. Most people had huge lands under cultivation. As the years passed, different kinds of building came around. People started to build houses in one area and various kinds of businesses came into existence. In this process people started to cut down trees. Due to this fact we know in many countries the agricultural output has also decreased. For who people who still cultivate agriculture, the land for cultivation has significantly decreased. Not only this with the increase in population, people need more places to stay. *

    Look into our personal internet page as well
    <.http://www.healthmedicinecentral.com/where-is-your-gallbladder/

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s